Irish house prices sky-high due to finance not scarcity

Property prices will fall when flows of money start to retreat

Ireland is just one country whose finite and fixed stock of land and property is massively inflated by an onslaught of unregulated capital. Photograph: David Davies/PA
Ireland is just one country whose finite and fixed stock of land and property is massively inflated by an onslaught of unregulated capital. Photograph: David Davies/PA

Economists regard the theory of supply and demand as nothing less than a “law” and as one of the fundamental principles governing “the economy”.

Almost every economic event or phenomenon is considered the product of the interaction of the laws of supply and demand, argues The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.

The “law” is currently being invoked by those who believe the solution to the Irish housing crisis is to simply build more houses. It is an analysis echoed regularly by grateful developers and estate agents.

But the “law” of supply and demand is a micro-economic concept and applicable only to the “economy” of individuals, households and firms.

READ MORE

The “economy” of a globalised country such as Ireland is, in stark contrast, a macro-economic concept, the result of analysing the aggregate activities of more than four million people operating within global markets for housing and other assets.

As evidence of the flawed nature of this fundamental micro-economic theory, we only have to look at Ireland’s housing market in 2006 – the year in which the market boomed before imploding catastrophically.

Irish home construction peaked in that year. In a country of just four million people, more than 90,000 homes were built. (By contrast the housing stock increased by just 8,800 between 2011 and 2016). And yet, despite this extraordinary increase in supply, and contrary to economic theory, prices in 2006 continued rising – by a whopping 11 per cent.

Further evidence can be found in the Irish housing market since 2006. One glance at the CSO’s 2016 census of housing stock makes clear that Ireland’s surplus stock is higher than it was in 1991 – then at 9.1 per cent. In 2016, the overall vacancy rate, including holiday homes, was 12.3 per cent. If holiday homes are excluded from the housing stock, the vacancy rate drops to 9.4 per cent. In 1991, Dublin’s surplus was 5.1 per cent of the total.

Inelastic land

To understand Ireland's housing crisis, and to formulate sound policy to deal with it, requires a macro-economic approach. As Josh Ryan-Collins and Laurie McFarlane argue in Rethinking the Economics of Land and Housing, land is inelastic, a gift of nature. It cannot be created and converted into capital.

It cannot be produced or reproduced, or “used up”. Above all, land (and property) is confined by boundaries. It cannot be moved out of Ireland.

The supply of credit, by contrast, is elastic and with the help of global central banks and financial institutions can be produced almost ad infinitum by both global but also Irish monetary and financial systems.

And unlike land, credit and capital are not confined by boundaries. In our globalised world, capital is highly mobile and its unregulated flows unreliable and unstable.

To understand Ireland’s housing crisis we need to lift our eyes from the micro- to the global macro-economy.

To follow “the Great Wall of Money” – $453 billion (€390 billion) – aimed at global markets in real estate.

Ireland is just one country whose finite and fixed stock of land and property is massively inflated by this onslaught of unregulated capital. Dublin as a major international financial centre attracted large volumes of unregulated, cross-border flows.

Above all, Dublin is host to valuable and scarce assets – property. The global owners of capital are in a frantic search for safe, high-yielding assets in which to park their capital.

At a time when Europe’s elites are committed to flawed economic austerity policies, there is a shortage of the very safe public assets preferred by global asset management funds or insurance companies: government debt (bonds or gilts).

As a result, those responsible for investing vast sums aim their billions at property markets which, while not as safe as government bonds, are nevertheless considered safer than other assets.

That explains why, €4.47 billion was invested in Irish commercial property in 2016 with total turnover 21 per cent higher than in the previous year.

Potent propellant

House prices have been blasted into the stratosphere, not because of a shortage of supply, but by the excess of a potent propellant – finance.

House prices will fall when the propellant is withdrawn – and flows of finance decline. Indeed, there are already signs that globally, capital flows are in retreat. Expect Irish house prices to follow suit.

There are already signs that globally, capital flows are in retreat. Expect Irish house prices to follow suit

To avoid a repetition of the crises of 2007, the Government and Irish political class have to understand the fundamental cause of rising house prices: the mobile, potent propellant that is global finance.

The economic establishment, both academic and professional, is not helpful in this regard. Indeed micro-economic reasoning has, to the relief of those profiting from the crisis, postponed and confused sound policymaking.

To prevent another financial crisis caused by falling house prices, government must manage the mobile capital flow of funds owned by asset management companies, private equity firms and vulture funds.

The Government purports to be committed to the security of its citizens. If so, then in a world of fixed land and mobile finance, politicians must ensure that capital flows are managed by public authority, not left to something beloved of neo-classical economics: the reckless “invisible hand”.

Ann Pettifor is director of Policy Research in Macroeconomics (Prime) and an adviser to Jeremy Corbyn, the leader of the Labour Party. She will deliver a keynote address at the FEPS-TASC annual conference on Friday